(
Part 1)
Xiaokai Yang, Economics: Neoclassical Framework versus New Classical, Blackwell Publishers (2001)
The normal economic system works itself. For its current operation it is under no central control, it needs no central survey. Over the whole range of human activity and human need, supply is adjusted to demand, and production to consumption, by a process that is automatic, elastic, and responsive..
J.A. Salter, Allied Shipping Control, p.16; quoted in D.H. Robertson (p.84)
Here and there, it is true, we have found islands of conscious power in this ocean of unconscious co-operation, like lumps of butter coagulating in a pail of buttermilk.
D.H. Robertson, The Control of Industry, Harcourt Brace (1923) p.84
For purposes of comparison, Prof. Yang explains the concept of neoclassical equilibrium (which he thinks is conceptually inferior to new classical analysis). The system of equations consists usually of a single representative agent who can chose between two goods, each of which has a representative production function. The need for a mathematically coherent solution imposes a lot of constraints, so that the production function nearly always takes the same form (these conditions, by the way, are known as the Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu conditions (Yang 2001, pp.101-103; see Rizvi 2006 for online explanation).
1
Usually, when neoclassical textbooks introduce utility functions, they go on to explain how students can derive demand functions from them. This textbook is not neoclassical, and it does not separate out consumers from producers (Yang, 2001, p.38). Instead, each consumer is also a producer who faces multiple possible production functions (for each possible good). In fact, Yang’s outline is a simplified version of
Sraffa’s [classical] general equilibrium, although Yang includes the production functions so students have something to solve.
Read more »Labels: economics